Sunday, July 30, 2006

GE CROPS: DRIVING FARMERS TO THE WALL?

Suman Sahai

Many crops of developing countries have a global value because of the special chemical compounds they contain like aromatic or other oils. If genetic engineering will modify common, commodity crops to produce these higher value chemicals, it will lead to displacement of the developing country products from valuable niche markets from where they can earn incomes, leading in turn to economic deprivation. Genetic engineering is providing alternative ways of producing commodities that have traditionally been supplied by developing countries. This has the potential of taking away the economic base of farmers who produce such products.

The production of High Fructose Corn Syrup (HFCS) from corn, a major GE crop bred for industrial applications like this, has undermined sugar prices and distorted sugar markets for cane sugar producers of developing countries like India. Surely, the massive agricultural subsidies of the EU and US for all agricultural products is a source of grave distortion in international agricultural trade but the creation of HFCS is also a major contributing factor in displacing cane sugar producers from the global sugar market.

Coconut is another victim of genetic engineering. Coconut provides high value oil used for edible and for industrial purposes. The main advantage of this oil is the high lauric acid that it contains. The US alone imports upwards of US$ 350 million worth of coconut and palm oil annually. Now genetic engineering is creating GE canola to produce the same special high lauric acid oil as coconut This research will have highly negative economic implications for farmers in coconut producing regions

Calgene has produced a high lauric acid rapeseed by using genes from the California Bay tree. This rapeseed will ultimately displace the coconut and palm kernel oil and deprive Asian farmers of revenues. The argument that coconut farmers could neverthelessl derive some income from other coconut products is being insensitive to the great difficulty with which developing country farmers are able to eke out a living. The loss of the coconut oil income, the farmers’ principal revenue opportunity in certain regions, will inflict severe economic hardship. This has to be understood in the context of the very limited opportunities for alternative or additional income sources in rural parts of Asia.

Intellectual Property Rights

The IPR issue, like much else in the GE story, is tailored for the corporations, not the farmers. It is an instrument that works against food and livelihood security and there is little evidence so far that it can contribute to increasing the production of food and removing poverty. Access to GE technology is largely impeded by the stringent IPRs that surround it.

Patent holders often refuse to license patents with broad claims to key technologies, to scientists and even to public sector institutions. Companies often seek patents not necessarily to conduct research themselves but to prevent research in areas that would threaten their monopoly. It is of concern that public research institutions are also getting into the patenting of plant technologies and research tools, further restricting access to genetic material and research data that are needed to cross complement research efforts.

Most of the basic technologies of genetic engineering are patented and the larger companies own these patents. These companies are reluctant to license many technologies to developing country organisations at an affordable cost. Patent laws do not require them to do so, so they are not obliged to grant any licenses if they prefer to control the technology themselves. This is part of the overall trend of corporate globalisation and it makes it very difficult for developing countries or public sector institutions to access new technologies or enter the research field.

Patents with an excessively broad claim are becoming increasingly problematic. They violate the ethical intent of patent law, which is to balance private gain with public good while leaving the way open for further innovation. Excessively broad claims like the one granted to Monsanto on all types of genetic transformation in all varieties of soybean (European Patent Number 301,749), are contrary to the original intention of patent law. They are monopoly instruments restricting useful research and therefore diminishing social welfare

The GURT technology

The Gene Use Restricting Technology (GURT) popularly known as the ‘terminator’ technology’ was kept in cold storage after widespread outrage at its anti-farmer focus but it is back on the corporate agenda and awaiting adoption.

GURT is an example of how genetic engineering has been used not to improve a crop or bring benefits to farmers but solely to enhance the control of the seed company over the variety they have bred. GURT is strictly speaking , the most stringent form of intellectual property rights, where the scientific process, not the legal, has been used to give the seed company complete control.

In the GURT technology two gene systems have been brought together to produce seeds with an in built mechanism that aborts development of the embryo so that germination can not take place and the seed is rendered sterile. The self -destructing seeds are actually hybrids produced by hybridising two transgenic plants, each containing one of the two gene systems. To control the induction sterility, a chemical switch has been built in. Soaking the seeds in a chemical like tetracycline can activate this switch. Once the tetracycline soaks into the seed tissue, it switches on one of the gene systems, which sets in motion the chemical process, which will abort the embryo. So in practice, the seed company can produce as much of the seed as they want and just before selling it to the farmer, they can treat the seeds with tetracycline to switch on the sterility inducing gene system.

When farmers buy this seed, they can grow one crop from it but the seed that sets in this crop on maturity, will not have the ability to germinate. The farmer will thus not be able to save viable seed from his crop for the next sowing and will be forced to return to the seed company for new seed. This establishes total control of the seed company on production and sale of seed. The terminator technology obviates the patent system in establishing the monopoly of the seed company on the new seed. The farmer is reduced to a helpless consumer.

Tuesday, July 4, 2006

Monsanto in the Dock: Appeals indictment by MRTPC

Suman Sahai

Monsanto's trade practices are under the scanner of the MRTPC for selling its Bt cotton varieties at very high prices

Mahyco-Monsanto Biotech India Ltd. (MMB) has been indicted by the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Commission for charging exorbitant rates for its Bt cotton varieties containing Monsanto's proprietary Bt gene and for exercising a monopoly in India. MMB has gone into appeal to the Supreme Court.

The introduction of Bt cotton by Mahyco-Monsanto Biotech in India has been marked by controversy that refuses to abate. Bt cotton was approved for the planting season in 2002 amidst objections by Gene Campaign and other civil society groups that the base variety used by Mahyco-Monsanto Biotech - the MECH cotton varieties - were rated at best as modest, not good performers. Subsequently in all the three years for which it had eceived provisional permission, the MMB cotton was found to fail in almost all the states where it was cultivated, its performance being particularly disastrous in Andhra Pradesh, Madhya Pradesh and Maharashtra.

Farmers suffered huge losses and the extreme indebtedness of resource poor farmers that led to tragic suicides was exacerbated by the exorbitantly priced MMB Bt cotton. Reports prepared by State Agriculture Departments echoed the findings of civil society groups like Gene Campaign, which had produced the first report on the field performance of Bt cotton and reported that over 60 percent of the farmers had suffered such heavy losses that they could not even recover their investment. (See table below). The Agriculture Minister of Andhra Pradesh conceded that Bt cotton had failed the farmers.

As against 300 to 400 per 450 gm bag charged for superior local cotton hybrids, MMB priced its Bt cotton at Rs1650 per bag, which they later raised to Rs 1800 per bag. Of the Rs 1650, Rs

1250 went to Monsanto as license fee for the use of Bt technology. Perhaps the license fee was increased when the price was hiked to Rs 1800. This is the highest license fee charged by Monsanto anywhere in the world. They charge about one-tenth this rate in China and Brazil. MMB also produces its Bt cotton in India as a hybrid, not as a true breeding variety. This consolidates their monopoly.

Farmers cannot save seeds from hybrids and must buy fresh seeds every season. In the case of true varieties, they can save seeds from their harvest and plant the next crop. Thus, the financial burden on the farmer is lowered. Besides, the Bt cotton strategy for pest control works better in a variety that contains two Bt genes rather than a hybrid containing only one Bt gene and is therefore only half as effective as the true variety.

After the failure of the Mahyco Monsanto Bt cotton, Gene Campaign had written to the then Agriculture Minister Sri Ajit Singh, making the demand that an enquiry should be conducted into the performance of Bt cotton and MMB be made to pay compensation to those farmers who had suffered losses. This is provided explicitly in the Indian law - the PPV-FR. MMB flatly refused to pay any compensation and neither the Ministry of Agriculture nor the GEAC (Genetic Engineering Approval Committee) took any action

Comparative income from Bt and Non-Bt cotton

FARM TYPE

NON-BT COTTON

BT COTTON


Farmers

Income/Acre

Net Profit/Acre

Farmers

Income

Net Profit/Acre


(Per Cent)

(Rs)

(Rs)

(Per Cent)

(Rs)

(Rs)

Low yieiding

35

7,394

2,661

60

5,637

-79

Medium yielding

58

12,512

7,779

35

9,737

4,021

High yielding

7

20,475

15,742

5

15,375

9,659

Ref. : Gene Campaign; Economic and Political Weekly, July 26, 2003.

against them. Subsequently, the AP (Andhra Pradesh) Government also claimed compensation from MMB for losses suffered by the farmers, a demand that was also rejected by the company, with the GEAC looking on.

The AP Government then banned the sale of MMB Bt cotton in the state. In the meanwhile, MMB had licensed the Bt technology to several Indian firms. On their initiative, the AP Government asked MMB to reduce the exorbitant license fees they were charging to something more reasonable, so that the seed could be more affordable to farmers. The steep price of GM cotton seeds was recognised as a major reason why the economics of Bt cotton was not working for many farmers. When MMB refused to do this, the AP Government and two farmer organisations moved the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Commission (MRTPC) against the company in January 2006 for charging "exorbitant" royalty for Bt Cotton.

On the instruction of the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Commission, the matter was investigated by the Director General of Investigation and Registration (DGIR). The DGIR report stated that MMB had failed to provide any rationale for the exorbitant license fees it charged. As there was no competition, the company was in a position to charge for the technology arbitrarily and unreasonably, thus establishing a monopoly. In an interim ruling, the MRTPC had directed Monsanto to reduce its technology fee in India to the rate it charged in China. Anticipating this, MMB had unilaterally reduced its license fee to Rs 900 per bag, but the MRTPC ruling could require Monsanto to cut down its license fee still further.

Having been indicted by the MRTPC, MMB has moved the Supreme Court challenging the order of the MRTPC directing it to fix a reasonable price for Bt cotton. It claims that the Commission has no jurisdiction to adjudicate on the issue as Intellectual Property Rights (IPR) issues and licensing of technology do not fall under the classification of goods or services; since there was no trade in goods. It may be pointed out here that by introducing IPRs into trade via the Trade Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) of the WTO, the WTO has, in fact, made IPRs as tradable goods, so MMB's position is without substance.

MMB further contends that there can be no case against it since the license fee is being charged for Monsanto's technology and know-how, which the sub-licensees further incorporate into their own seeds. This contention is also baseless. The sub-licensee for this gene construct is Mahyco Monsanto Biotech India Ltd (MMB), a joint venture between Monsanto and Mahyco. This means that the company has licensed the technology to itself. Further, the case is against the price of Bt cotton sold by the name of 'Bollgard', which incorporates the specific Bt gene construct patented and owned by Monsanto.

MMB further claims that there was no rule or guideline prescribed in the Indian law to determine the prices that a technology provider could charge from its sub-licensees. This assertion of the company is easily struck down by the provisions of the Competition Act,

which specifically prohibits any agreement between enterprises engaged in similar trade of goods as Monsanto and MMB are, which directly or indirectly determine the purchase or sale price.

MMB asserts that nothing in the law prevents an inventor of a new and useful product from allowing a person to use his product on payment of a fee for such use regardless of whether the inventor held a patent under the Indian law or not. When the patent law is applied in the same spirit, which recognises intellectual property with or without a patent grant, Section 83 (c) of the Patent Act can be invoked, which states quite clearly that the protection and enforcement of patent rights must contribute to the promotion of the technological innovation and to the transfer and dissemination of technology to the mutual advantage of producers and users of technological knowledge and in a manner conducive to social and economic welfare, and to a balance of rights and obligations. Section 83 (d) further says that the patent granted should act as an instrument to promote public interest especially in the sectors of vital importance for socio-economic and technological development in India.

Both provisions make Mahyco-Monsanto's position untenable.

In a further desperate bid to fight its indictment, Mahyco-Monsanto Biotechnology has submitted to the Supreme Court that its technology is in the nature of undisclosed information or trade secret. This is a misrepresentation and absolutely incorrect. The Bt technology is no secret. On the contrary, its identity and composition is very well known. The Bt construct used in Monsanto's Bollgard has been patented; a fundamental requirement on the grant of a patent is disclosure of the patentable subject matter. So, all the details of the Bt technology used in Bollgard cotton, which is being used in India, is in fact in the public domain and cannot be considered "undisclosed information" or "trade secret" by any stretch of the imagination. Further, it has been licensed widely in many countries of the world so the Bt cotton know-how has been passed on several times to a number of parties. There is nothing undisclosed or secretive about it. A trade secret is where the composition of the product is completely secret. For instance, Coca Cola protects its special soft drinks formula by a trade secret and this formula is not licensed to anyone. The recipe is undisclosed information and no one knows what is in it. That is not the case with the Bt technology.

The Supreme Court will certainly be able to see that the Mahyco-Monsanto case is entirely baseless. A correct decision invoking the law, especially the public interest components of it, will hopefully set down the conditions for technology transfer in India and prevent greedy corporations from exploiting Indian farmers, under the guise of introducing superior technology.