By FRED PEARCE
Will agricultural
intensification save our natural ecosystems from farmer invasion?
He is the most revered figure in agricultural research – the
father of the green revolution. But the
late Norman Borlaug’s influence extends further even than delivering the seeds
that have fed the world. He also
established in agricultural and environmental orthodoxy what is known today as
the Borlaug hypothesis — the idea that intensifying agriculture is also the key
to saving forests and other natural ecosystems from invasion by farmers.
The idea underpins research priorities in agriculture, for
which increased yield is to holy grail.
More surprisingly perhaps, it sustains conservationists who want to
abandon green notions of low-intensity organic agriculture in favour of giving
agriculture its head.
Now the argument is being deployed in the debate over a
future global climate change deal. Some
advocates of REDD, which would provide finance for protecting forests as carbon
stores, say carbon offsetters should be encouraged to fund intensified farming
too. It is one facet of the push for
“climate-smart” agriculture that we will heard again at the next climate talks
in Doha later this year.
Lord Nicholas Stern, the British economist behind the highly
influential Stern Review on the economics of climate change, puts the Borlaug
hypothesis this way: “Cattle pasture in Brazil has only one animal per hectare. Raise that to two animals and you can save
the Amazon rainforest.”
But is it true? If
farming were a zero-sum game, with a simple aim of growing enough food to feed
the world, then clearly intensification should spare land for nature. But market forces may have perverse effects.
The Contrarian View
The counter-argument is that farmers don’t clear forests to
feed the world; they clear forests to make money. So helping farmers become more efficient and
productive won’t reduce the threat. It
will increase it, by encouraging them to expand, and increasing their resources
to do it.
As Tony Simons, deputy director of the World Agroforestry
Centre in Nairobi, put it to me a year or so back: “Borlaug thought that if you
addressed poverty in the forest border, they’d stop taking their machetes into
the forest. Actually, they get enough
money to buy a chainsaw and do much more damage.”
Recent studies give weight to this contrarian view. Thomas Rudel of Rutgers University, New
Jersey, compared national trends in agricultural yields and how much land is
under crops. If Borlaug was right, then
countries with fast-rising yields should see less increase in croplands,
perhaps even a decrease. Sadly, he found
no such link.
Robert Ewers of the Zoological Society of London reported
that increased yields of staple food crops do not spare the land, but
stimulated increased planting of other crops, including non-food crops like
cotton, rubber and biofuels. As a
result, he concluded, “land sparing is a weak process that only occurs under a
limited set of circumstances.”
Economists are not
surprised
That’s how markets work, they say. Arild Angelsen, of the Norwegian University
of Life Sciences and senior associate at CIFOR, modelled the competing
influences and concluded that, contrary to the Borlaug hypothesis, “local yield
increases tend to stimulate agricultural encroachment”.
Globalization increases the stimulus. After all, Brazil’s assault on the Amazon in
the late 20th century was driven not by an imperative to feed its own
population, but by its successful drive to become the world’s biggest
agricultural exporter. Similarly only a
fraction of the palm oil grown on Indonesia’s former forests is for domestic
use.
Rudel has suggested that the Borlaug hypothesis is confounded
by a modern version of the Jevons paradox.
The 19th century British economist William Jevons pointed out that
during the industrial revolution, increased efficiency in coal burning led to
more coal being burned, rather than less. Similarly today, more intensive
agriculture may stimulate rather than defuse the clearance of land for new
farms.
Can the Borlaug
hypothesis help tackle climate change?
There are other reasons to question Stern’s suggestion that
the Borlaug hypothesis could help tackle climate change. Even if agriculture did spare forests, it
also massively increases farming’s carbon footprint. Might those emissions swamp any gains from
protecting forests?
A study by Jennifer Burney and others at Stanford in 2010
suggested not. After balancing both
influences, she estimated a net benefit to the atmosphere from agricultural
intensification of 590 billion tonnes of carbon dioxide in the past 50 years.
But surely that depends on the timescale you use. A mature forest is can only sequester so much
carbon, while agricultural emissions continue for as long as the land is
cultivated. Run the clock forward and
the balance may be reversed.
None of this is to say that intensification won’t be
needed. The world has to be fed, after
all. But the simple belief that deploying agribusiness to
drive up farm yields will deliver forest protection seems economically
illiterate. And the even simpler notion
that investment in the intensification of agriculture can have a direct carbon
payback seems dangerous folly.
About the Author:
Fred Pearce is a journalist and author based in London,
UK. He writes regularly for New
Scientist magazine, the Guardian newspaper and Yale e360 web site. His books include Peoplequake, When the
Rivers Run Dry and, mostly recently, The Land Grabbers.
No comments:
Post a Comment